Sowing Scarcity: Syria’s Wheat Regime from Self-Sufficiency to Import-Dependency

A wheat field in Beshindlaye, Syria. Photo by Frank Kidner via Wikimedia Commons. A wheat field in Beshindlaye, Syria. Photo by Frank Kidner via Wikimedia Commons.

Sowing Scarcity: Syria’s Wheat Regime from Self-Sufficiency to Import-Dependency

By : Rohan Advani

In 2020, the Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) estimated that 9.3 million people in Syria were considered to be food insecure, making it one of the ten countries hardest hit by acute food insecurity. The war has stressed the government’s ability to provide bread at low prices. Shortages have become commonplace. In a speech on 4 May 2020, President Bashar al-Assad even admitted that “Syria’s most difficult internal challenge is securing basic goods, especially foodstuffs.” Three months later, a devastating explosion at the Port of Beirut destroyed a critical port of entry and storage facility for Syria’s wheat imports.

Syria’s wheat crisis is by no means simply a war-time predicament. Environmental degradation was a key legacy of Syria’s bid for food self-sufficiency in the 1980s and 1990s. In the 2000s, a series of environmental disasters and the overall neglect of Syrian agricultural workers precipitated an acute crisis in food security that the Syrian government avoided by abandoning its strategy of self-sufficiency in favor of wheat imports. However, a reliance on imports ultimately paved the way for the rise of black markets and private traders close to the Syrian regime during the conflict. In effect, the war exacerbated pre-war trends that emerged amidst the transformation of Syria’s food regime from a system of self-sufficiency to one of import dependency.

Nine years of war has also undermined agricultural productive capacity and provoked an exodus of Syrian farmers, curtailing the possibility of returning to a strategy of self-sufficiency. Syrian government bombardment of formerly opposition-held areas and the territorial loss of agricultural regions in the northeast has meant that its previous strategy remains a path foreclosed. Moreover, international sanctions on Syria, which also predate the war, have further restricted the government’s ability to conduct import trade through legitimate channels, hastening the proliferation of offshore shell companies and illegal smuggling routes across the country’s porous borders. Syria’s partial integration into a hostile global financial system has put its reliance on importing wheat under great duress.

In 2020, numerous news reports described the long queues for bread proliferating throughout cities as the Syrian government resorted to providing rationed quantities of subsidized bread on the controversial smart card system. Increasingly, Syrians are also complaining of the declining quality of bread and the exorbitant prices being charged on the black market. With the government unable to move away from an import-dependency model, while simultaneously struggling to source badly needed imports, Syrians will likely face these problems for the foreseeable future.

The Pre-War Roots of Syria’s Wheat Crisis


The roots of Syria’s wheat crisis stretch back to the country’s tumultuous experience with economic liberalization and environmental degradation in the 1990s and early 2000s. Decades prior to the current conflict, in a bid to establish food self-sufficiency, the Syrian state developed extensive irrigation projects and provided direct wheat subsidies and indirect water subsidies to intensify wheat production. The goal of self-sufficiency in wheat and barley production was achieved in 1994.[1] 

However, groundwater and soil resources in agricultural regions in the north and northeast were exhausted in the process. The effects this environmental degradationcoupled with the neglect of agricultural sector workers in the 2000swere felt acutely by inhabitants during the 1999-2001 and 2006-2010 droughts, as evidenced by increasing poverty and rural-urban migration. Between 2008 and 2009, the UN estimates that 800,000 people lost their livelihoods due to the drought, with 200-300,000 people migrating out of the northeastern province of Hasakah alone, although some of these figures have been contested.[2] 

Regardless of the precise numbers, the damage from the droughts and long-term agrarian decline did not push the government to support Syrian agricultural workers and rural households. In the mid-2000s, the Syrian government actually reduced its subsidies for agricultural inputs, namely pesticides, fertilizers, and even diesel. Between 2006 and 2010, food prices increased by 38.2% while energy prices doubled.[3] At the same time, the government opened Syrian markets to cheap Turkish and Jordanian agricultural exports, forcing small-scale producers out of the market, and leaving them to search for other forms of work in urban centers or for heavily capitalized agricultural firms.

The decline in Syria’s agricultural sector in the decade before the war was palpable. From 2001 to 2007, agriculture’s contribution to GDP decreased from 27% to 18%.[4] The country’s population grew and rural-urban migration swelled, meanwhile the annual average growth of cereal yield decreased from 14% in 2000-2005 to 7% in 2006-2011. Taking into account population growth from 1990-2010, Syria’s agricultural growth per capita actually declined in real terms, averaging -3.1% over this twenty-year period.[5] In 2008, traders and state institutions were called upon for the first time to procure wheat on a large scale to make up for massive wheat deficits, importing approximately 1.2 million tons (approximately 30% of the pre-war average wheat output). To avert a crisis of food security in the mid to late 2000s, the Syrian state gradually dispensed with its strategy of food self-sufficiency in favor of importsfurther marginalizing agricultural producers and strengthening private sector traders in the process. 

Outside of the agricultural sector, presidential decrees and legislation that liberalized sectors of the economy in the 2000s brought in foreign direct investment (and foreign currencies), primarily into the sectors of oil and gas, tourism, real estate, insurance, and private banking.[6] The reorganization of Syria’s political economy in favor of commercial sectors gradually embedded the country into global trade and financial networks that had previously been sealed off. Foreign currencies became more accessible to traders and the new private banking system allowed political and economic elites to transfer their money outside of the country. In this interlude, a new crop of urban businessmen such as Firas Tlass and Rami Makhlouf amassed great economic and political power, while the Syrian regime sidelined the old Ba’athist leadership that had protected rural producers. 

Syrian Agriculture under Fire


While these pre-war trends signaled a shift toward a reliance on imports, Syria enjoyed only a short period of relative stability in the supply of wheat. The outbreak of militarized conflict following the popular uprisings of 2011 marked a watershed moment in determining Syria’s trajectory towards food insecurity.  

Less than three years into the conflict, as farmers fled war-torn areas and saw their livelihoods turn to ruins, domestic production halved. Even as the government began to retake control of key areas, domestic production remained far below its pre-2011 levels; in 2018, wheat production stood at just 1.2 million tonsthe lowest it had been since 1989. Of the 140 wheat collection centers that were in operation in Syria before 2011, only 40 remained in 2017. Additionally, four out of five yeast factories in the country shut down completely, challenging the state’s capacity to provide plentiful bread at low prices.[7] The militarization of the conflict inflicted severe damage on Syrian agricultural production and destroyed sources of rural livelihood. 

Given the national importance of wheat and the provision of bread as a signifier of credible governance, government forces specifically targeted agricultural heartlands over the course of the war, further straining already-stressed domestic wheat sources. In opposition-held areas, the Syrian government’s wide-scale bombing campaigns devastated wheat production and refinement. In the southern province of Dara’a, for example, flour mills and bakeries were targeted by the Syrian government and key provisions were cut off, forcing residents to rely on assistance from international NGOs, USAID, networks of Syrian revolutionaries in Amman, and the Jordanian government.[8] In opposition-held Aleppo, Human Rights Watch reported ten government aerial bombings of bakeries over a three-week period in August, 2012. In Idlib province, farmers claimed that government forces were intentionally targeting wheat crops to prevent opposition fighters from hiding in the fields. According to a local network of media activists in Idlib, the Syrian government launched more than 125 air raids on villages after the Islamist-led Jaysh al-Fateh seized the strategic Abu al-Duhur airbase in September 2015. As Martinez and Eng note in their study of the politics of bread in the Syrian Civil War, “when the Free Syrian Army and other rebels thrived in the regions of Idlib, Homs, and Deir e-Zor, bakery bombings quickly followed.”[9]

On the other hand, groups such as ISIS regularly used the threat of fires to extort money from farmers under its control. When ISIS began to lose territory throughout the northeast, it intentionally set crops ablaze, stating in its newsletter that, “the harvest season is still long, and we tell the soldiers of the Caliphate: you have before you millions of dunums of land planted with wheat and barley, which are owned by apostates.” However, these tactics were not limited to ISIS; when fires broke out across the northeast, residents accused all military actors of setting fire to crops, including Syrian government forces, Turkish-backed factions, and the Syrian Democratic Forces (SDF).

With the Syrian government increasingly cash-strapped and state institutions no longer holding a monopoly over wheat purchases, power shifted toward local brokers and traders who worked alongside the regime.

In addition to targeted bombings, agricultural areas saw the spread of deadly fires that destroyed thousands of hectares of agricultural land, specifically wheat crops in northeast and northwest Syria. Although some fires may have been accidental, the militarization of these areas compounded the risk of agricultural destruction. Caught between military factions firing shells and incendiary bombs, some farmers witnessed their entire wheat crops burned to the ground and their livelihoods destroyed. Climate change-induced temperature rises and droughts also increased the chances of accidental fires, whether from the destruction of agricultural equipment during military skirmishes, or even from cigarette butts dropped by soldiers in the area. The Autonomous Administration of North and East Syria (AA), also known as Rojava, made efforts to use certain herbicides that create vegetation-free strips of earth so as to limit the spread of fires, but these come as limited solutions in the face of ongoing military conflict.

Control over grain storage facilities also shaped the contours of local governance and relations between various political forces throughout the war. For example, in the city of Manbij, management over an important grain silo was hotly contested, passing through the hands of the regime, the opposition-led local councils, ISIS, and the SDF. In 2013, under local council rule, the Council of the Trustees of the Revolution (CTR) raised the price of bread, much to the anger of residents in the area. As one ex-member of the CTR told me, “ISIS was claiming that the local council was stealing wheat and rising bread prices, so when they [ISIS] took over [the silo], they brought down the price of bread to prove their governing capabilities.” In 2014, the silos then sustained damage from US-led airstrikes, which also killed some of its workers. Then in 2016, during the US-backed SDF assault on Manbij, ISIS concentrated on defending this position, planting mines and booby traps around the grain silo to prevent advancing troops from entering. Ultimately, US and SDF forces took the town from ISIS and asserted control over the silo. Yet despite the symbolic and strategic significance of grain, the silo is now used by the SDF-led Manbij Military Council to host its military headquarters rather than as storage for grain.  

As a result of territorial fragmentation and prolonged violence, border crossings and black markets emerged throughout the country. With the Syrian government increasingly cash-strapped and state institutions no longer holding a monopoly over wheat purchases, power shifted toward local brokers and traders who worked alongside the regime. Traders often purchased wheat from opposition-held areas by offering above-market prices; activists from Raqqa and Deir e-Zor even accused the government of using middlemen to purchase wheat from ISIS. The rearrangement of Syria’s political economy toward trade intermediaries was also reflected at the elite level, as some sections of the pre-war bourgeoisie found themselves increasingly marginalized in favor of war-profiteers such as Mohammad and Hussam al-Qatarji, Khodr Ali Taher, Samer Foz, and Wassim Qattan. 

Challenges to the Import-Dependency Model


Alongside the military destruction of Syrian agriculture and the proliferation of black markets, the government’s ability to maintain the smooth flow of wheat from abroad and purchase wheat directly from Syrian farmers came under severe duress throughout the course of the war.

For example, the government gradually lost its monopoly over the wheat market as the war progressed. The General Establishment for Cereal Processing and Trade (GECPT/Hoboob), a state-owned enterprise that had historically purchased the lion’s share of the country’s wheat grown by its farmers, no longer dominated the domestic market. In 2011, GECPT purchased 64% of the country’s domestic wheat, but by 2017, this figure dropped to just 17%.  Moreover, as early as 2013, more than 50% of GECPT’s wheat purchases originated from abroadmainly from Russia and Ukraine and delivered via Lebanese and Syrian ports. Using Lebanese front companies to access US dollars and bypass suffocating US sanctions, Syrian businessmen close to the regime acted as important trade intermediaries for the purchasing of wheat. For example, in 2019, the head of GECPT identified three companies that were awarded tenders for the import of wheat in the previous year, two of which were registered in Lebanon as offshore companiesone owned by an important affiliate of the regime, Samer Foz.

However, with the onset of the spiraling financial crisis in Lebanon and the falling value of the Syrian lira in late 2019, the government’s import strategy that had dramatically intensified over the past decade began to unravel quickly. In an attempt to meet domestic requirements, GECPT made a bid to source 200,000 tons of wheat from Russia in February 2020, but ultimately failed to complete the purchases, most likely due to US dollars frozen in the Lebanese financial system. Moreover, as the COVID-19 pandemic engulfed the globe, Russia announced on April 26 that it had reached its grain export quota for the April-June period and would halt all shipments of grain until July 1.

Scrambling to source enough grain for its population, the Syrian government announced in May that it was dedicating 11% of its budgetapproximately 450 billion SYPto purchase the local wheat harvest. The majority of this wheat, however, is grown in Syria’s northern and northeastern regions of Hasakah, Raqqa, Aleppo, Deir e-Zor, and Hamamost of which are now under the control of the AA. With the Syrian government pitted in competition with the AA over the purchasing of wheat, the two sides entered into a price war amid a rapid collapse in the value of the Syrian lira. On June 7, the AA announced that it would no longer be giving a price in Syrian pounds until the market stabilized and would set aside a certain amount of US dollars for the crop. In the interim, Russia resumed its international export of wheat, allowing the Syrian government to issue more tenders for wheat imports. On August 2, the Tartous Manager of GECPT confirmed that 25,000 tons of wheat had arrived into the Port of Tartous.

These remain temporary solutions to an underlying, structural problem of import dependency and foreign currency shortages in Syria. Opening its economy to foreign investment in the early 2000s led to an influx of capital in the oil and gas, tourism, real-estate, and banking sectors. But now with oil and gas fields largely outside of government control, tourism at an almost complete standstill, and the economy unable to rebuild from suffocating sanctions, Syria’s dependence on imports has generated an acute crisis, exerting immense pressure on its currency reserves. In addition to wheat, the government has recently faced similar problems in issuing tenders to import raw sugar and ricecommodities that are supposed to be sold at subsidized prices. Through a combination of price increases and temporary solutions, the government has hobbled along, trying to stave off massive food shortages throughout the country.

Uneven Global Integration and Perpetual Crisis


This situation is not uncommon for many import-dependent developing countries integrated into the US-led global financial system. Unlike countries that follow a model of export-oriented growth which build up foreign currency reserves (which are then often recycled back to the US in the form of treasury bonds), import-dependent countries struggle to accumulate these reserves and are therefore subject to demand crises and external price shocks. However, the absence of an alternative financial system means that a heavily sanctioned country, like Syria, experiences further political difficulties in both generating foreign reserves and using them on the international market. The result is a downward spiral: as pathways for accumulating reserves are foreclosed, fears of reserve shortages induce bouts of speculation and hoarding that threaten the value of the national currency, thereby weakening peoples’ incomes and importing inflation. Largely cut off from the global financial system yet dependent upon external sources of grain and food provision, Syria has been pushed deeper into the orbit of competing powers such as Russia and Iran.

Syria, like other countries, is nonetheless a society stratified by various social classes with competing political and economic interests. As such, the effects of food insecurity, import dependency, and US sanctions are not spread equally throughout Syrian society. In an attempt to mask its own exploitation and subordinate class conflict to national unity, the Assad regime regularly denounces Western imperialism and criticizes US sanctions. Yet Syrian elites are often least affected by the deteriorating economy as they store their wealth in places like Dubai, Lebanon, and Switzerland. The uneven terrain of global finance allows anti-imperialist elites to exploit financial hubs and amass great wealth even as imperialist powers seek to exclude such countries from the global financial system. 

The sordid underside of this arrangement, however, is a great number of Syrians shouldering the burden of such exclusion. Farmers are forced to import agricultural inputs at much higher prices with little state support while fires continue to burn crops in agricultural regions. For many Syrian agricultural workers who fled the country, fears of conscription and government retribution sit alongside the reality of returning to few economic opportunities. At the same time, citizens throughout the country face alarming rates of poverty and hunger as bread shortages become commonplace. Households are sold rationed quantities of bread depending on the size of their families, sometimes waiting three hours for their allocation. Meanwhile, some bakeries have increased their prices fifteen-fold for those who can afford itor who cannot afford to wait. The provision of food has become tethered to networks of exploitative trade monopolists and emerging black markets as the government fails to source enough wheat and rebuild bakeries. 

Even though the presidential palace continues to regularly denounce corruption and scapegoat traders in a bid to shore up popular support, the persistence of such trade networks and diminishing food security is an outgrowth of the regime’s sources of political power within an exclusivist global economy. To crack down on trading networks and emerging black markets in any comprehensive manner would in fact undermine sources of elite power that are central to reproducing class rule in Syria. Nevertheless, without public control over food imports, without loosening international sanctions, and without revitalizing Syria’s agricultural areas in environmentally-sustainable ways that protect rural producers, the future of Syria’s food security remains in doubt.  



[1] Jane Harrigan, The Political Economy of Arab Food Sovereignty (Springer, 2014), 46.


[2] Professor of Politics and International Relations, Jan Selby, has scrutinized some of these figures, noting that they were often exaggerated or taken out of context to justify exceptional environmental narratives about the origins of the Syrian conflict. Instead, he emphasizes the importance of long-term agrarian decline in Syria, pointing to the fact that Hasakah witnessed dramatic out-migration even before the drought. Jan Selby, "Climate change and the Syrian civil war, Part II: The Jazira’s agrarian crisis." Geoforum 101 (2019): 260-274.


[3] Linda Matar, The Political Economy of Investment in Syria (Springer, 2017), 148.


[4] Selby, 266.


[5] Harrigan, 23.


[6] Matar, 129.


[7] Martínez, José Ciro, and Brent Eng. "Struggling to Perform the State: The Politics of Bread in the Syrian Civil War." International Political Sociology 11.2 (2017): 136.


[8] Martínez, José Ciro. "Topological Twists in the Syrian Conflict: Re-thinking Space through Bread." Review of International Studies 46.1 (2020): 121-136.


[9] Martinez and Eng, 138.

  • ALSO BY THIS AUTHOR

    • A Pit(i)less Blame Game at the Beirut Port of Institutional Corruption

      A Pit(i)less Blame Game at the Beirut Port of Institutional Corruption

      After the explosion of 2,750 tons of ammonium nitrate at the Port of Beirut on August 4, half of the port was completely destroyed and sections of the city adjacent to it have become uninhabitable. The explosion claimed the lives of 191 victims, a death toll not yet settled, from firefighters, port and migrant workers, to nearby residents. Several are still missing. Three hundred thousand people have lost their homes in a city already facing a severe housing crisis fueled by years of real estate speculation. Residents of this country, whose ruling class has engaged in systematic plunder, redistributing wealth away from the masses to a small sliver, now have to confront the fallout of urban destruction and further dispossession wrought by political and economic schemes planned behind closed doors.

The Agrarian Question in Lebanon Today: A View from a Camp in the Bekaa Valley

Conventional media portrayals of Syrian refugees in Lebanon evoke a familiar image: women and children standing wide-eyed in front of their modest white tarpaulin tents, with the ubiquitous blue UNHCR logo serving as a reminder of their seemingly temporary status. Against the backdrop of Lebanon’s deepening economic and other crises over the past several years, Syrians have become convenient scapegoats for the country’s problems within the discourse of right-wing politicians and segments of the Lebanese public. The trope of “Syrian overpopulation,” rooted in the stereotyped figure of the aid-dependent refugee, has served as a justification for stricter controls of Syrians’ cross-border and internal mobility. And yet, the vast majority of Syrians are not idly waiting in camps for UN aid, nor are they a drain on Lebanon’s economy. From construction, to agriculture, to delivery services, Syrians form the very backbone of Lebanon’s low-wage labor force, alongside other migrant populations. In fact, significant numbers of Syrians registered as refugees have been working as seasonal labor migrants in Lebanon for decades. Even newcomers are often connected to long-standing networks of village-level labor recruitment rooted in previous migrations from Syria to Lebanon. 

As an anthropologist, I spent eighteen months working with Syrian farmworker-refugees in Lebanon’s agricultural heartland, the Bekaa Valley. Much of my fieldwork took place in a camp run by a shaweesh[i] (headman) from Aleppo, who I will pseudonymously call Abu Sharif. He is one among hundreds of shaweesh in Lebanon who provide shelter and work opportunities to Syrians through an elaborate agricultural labor-recruiting system. As an upwardly-mobile former labor migrant from Syria who has accumulated enough capital and social connections to establish a camp in Lebanon, Abu Sharif recruits Syrians in need of jobs and affordable housing. Though shaweesh camps (locally known as warshat)[ii] have existed for decades, the network of camps they operate expanded significantly after Syrians began to flee to Lebanon en masse after the 2011 Syrian popular uprising devolved into a protracted war.  Since then, most of the shaweesh camps have expanded and are registered with the United Nations as refugee camps, but they are still referred to by their residents as warshat. Hailing from the poorest regions of Syria, the precarious refugee-workers who reside in these camps provide a highly flexible supply of cheap labor to virtually every farm in the Bekaa Valley.

It is increasingly evident that Lebanon faces an imminent food crisis. This is an outcome of a series of converging economic, environmental, and epidemiological shocks that have sent food prices soaring. This crisis has been compounded by a devastating explosion that destroyed Lebanon’s main port of Beirut and much of its surroundings. Such dynamics reflect a broader global crisis of food production. Amidst decades of liberalizing labor regulations and privatizing public agricultural institutions and resources, one of the defining features of today’s “neoliberal food regime”[iii] is the massive migration of landless and land-poor farmers in search of waged work across borders. Within Lebanon’s agricultural sector, this role has been crucially filled by Syrian migrant laborers who, for the past several decades, have migrated seasonally across the border to plant, harvest, and weed virtually every type of fruit and vegetable upon which Lebanese consumers depend.

The expansion of the shaweesh camp system parallels the application of the Economic Reform and Market Liberalization (al-islah al-iqtisadi wa- tahrir al-suq) in Syria. With the collapse of the Soviet Union, and particularly following the accession of Bashar al-Assad to the Syrian presidency in 2000, the country's centrally planned economy progressively shifted away from the Ba'thist paradigm of state-controlled “food self-sufficiency” toward increasing embeddedness in the globalized market economy.[iv] This was epitomized by Syria’s signing of the General Arab Free Trade Agreement (GAFTA) in 2005, slashing state-subsidized goods (tamwin), privatization of state-owned farms in the Euphrates Basin, and subjecting previously state-mandated prices to a competitive market dominated by regional traders and agro-processing capital.[v] According to some estimates, from 2002 to 2008 Syria lost forty percent of its agricultural workforce—in part as a result of Law 56 of 2004 that weakened tenancy protections by allowing landlords to replace long-term tenancy agreements with temporary contracts.[vi] The devastating effects of these economic reforms on Syria’s poorest populations were exacerbated by a series of recurrent droughts from 2007 to 2012. This led to mass migrations of destitute rural populations in search of waged work to Syria’s cities and further west to Lebanon.[vii] Many of the workers in Abu Sharif’s camp, like other shaweesh camp residents, were part of this wave of migration of displaced sharecroppers, agro-pastoralists, and subsistence farmers from Eastern Syria collectively known as shawaya.[viii] Their migrations exemplify the contemporary problem of “dispossession by displacement”,[ix] defined by increasing global migrations of farmers dispossessed through direct force or the compulsion of economic forces. When the Syrian uprising began in 2011, many of the first protests took place in rural and peri-urban areas coping with economic dislocation. As this popular uprising devolved into a brutal conflict that persists nine years later, it is the rural poor of Syria who have borne the brunt of the devastation wrought by war. 

In tandem with the rise of seasonal migration from Syria to Lebanon, Lebanon has featured a steady decline in the viability of small-scale farming in the last fifty years. The decades leading up to the Lebanese Civil War (1975-1990) included the proliferation of large capitalist farms in the Bekaa Valley, Akkar, and the southern coastal plain, where citrus, sugar beets, and potatoes were grown.[x] This marked the emergence of a growing Lebanese “agro-exporting bourgeoisie” composed of Lebanese traders from major cities and the diaspora.[xi] As production became dominated by this new class of wealthy capitalist farmers, large numbers of small-holding or landless Lebanese farmers began working on these large plantations as sharecroppers and agricultural wage laborers. Others began migrating to Lebanon’s cities or abroad in search of work. By the eve of the Lebanese Civil War (1975), an estimated forty percent of Lebanon’s entire rural population had left the countryside—swelling the ranks of the urban proletariat.[xii] This dynamic of proletarianization continued throughout Lebanon’s postwar transition from 1990 onward, as large-scale land purchases became an increasingly attractive investment for Lebanon’s elite classes, particularly wealthy emigrés. As part of the postwar consensus, Lebanon engaged in a path of aggressive trade liberalization, bolstered by GAFTA, which lowered prices for Lebanese consumers, but has been detrimental to small farmers.[xiii] Rising land rents placed the possibility of deriving a secure livelihood from farming further beyond the reach of most Lebanese. As a result, Lebanon’s agricultural sector faces a problem of “generational succession”,[xiv] in which the majority of Lebanese rural youth must pursue off-farm employment in lieu of or alongside agriculture in order to survive.

It is against this historical backdrop that the intensification of Syrian labor migration to Lebanon must be understood. As Abu Ahmad, a Lebanese shaweesh who runs a camp near Abu Sharif explained to me, “Before the warshat (shaweesh camps), we used to work small pieces of land cooperatively with my family’s labor. Now, what happened? The (Lebanese) small farmer has practically disappeared. Now it is just a few big farmers who have capital.” He goes on: “When there were small farmers like us in Lebanon . . . I would rent fifty dunum of land for the season using just my family’s labor and we could actually make a living from farming. We did not need to hire Syrian workers. I became a shaweesh when I could not survive from farming anymore.” Lebanese agriculturalists are constantly adjusting their production to an unregulated local and regional export market, which has led to the growing concentration of wealth into the hands of a privileged few with access to the necessary capital to remain competitive. Within this competitive market, Lebanese producers have sought to reduce production costs by driving down wages and relying on more labor-intensive cultivation techniques. Long-standing Syrian migrants and small Lebanese farmers capitalized on this shift in labor demand through the creation of the shaweesh camp system. These camps serve as low-cost sources of housing and services for poor Syrian labor migrants who otherwise would not be able to afford the relatively high cost of living in Lebanon. In this way, they sustain the outsourcing of labor by absorbing the costs of reproduction that would normally be covered by the Lebanese state. Thus, contrary to the simplistic trope that Syrians are “stealing” Lebanese jobs, Abu Ahmad’s narrative makes clear that the displacement of small-scale Lebanese farmers and concomitant reliance on Syrian migrant labor were driven by the shifting imperatives of agrarian capitalist accumulation.

Prior to 2011, Syrian nationals were permitted to spend six months as temporary residents in Lebanon, returning frequently to Syria for health care, schooling, and subsidized goods.  As Abu Sharif explained to me, “Before the war, all of the workers used to come back at the beginning of summer to work. They would bring a tent made of animal hide (bayt sha’r) from their villages, just a basic cover, since you do not need much in the warm, summer months. And then we would take the tents back to Syria with us in the winter and come back the following summer.” Since the conflict in Syria began, many of these formerly seasonal workers have effectively become stuck in Lebanon.  Thus, they must cope with the higher costs of living in Lebanon year-round. Facing the dual loss of social benefits from the Syrian welfare state and a source of seasonal subsistence from their land in Syria, many refugees have become increasingly dependent on labor opportunities offered by shaweesh camps. 

Abu Sharif’s camp functions through a credit-debt system, in which newly arrived Syrian refugee-workers go into debt to the shaweesh for the cost of their tent and their yearly rent, as well as everyday consumption needs, health care, and major occasions such as weddings, bridewealth payments, and funerals. In exchange, Abu Sharif is responsible for securing agricultural jobs for camp residents, negotiating payment and working hours with Lebanese employers, and transporting the camp residents to their jobs in his flatbed truck.  As is typically the case in shaweesh camps, Abu Sharif resides in a tent in the camp alongside the workers, including members of his extended family. He is the only member of the camp with a Lebanese bank account, and thus with access to hard cash. As such, he has taken on the function of a moneylender for the indebted, cash-poor Syrian refugee-workers living in his camp. Abu Sharif is expected to lend money when workers request it, which he records in his monthly ledger (jarad). His accounting system is measured in terms of year-long seasonal commitments for each tent in the camp. Those who remain indebted, which is usually the majority, are obliged to stay in the camp and keep working for the upcoming year. Those who have worked off their debt have the option to leave the camp, work in a different camp, or go back to Syria.

Throughout the war in Syria, shaweesh camps’ distributive practices have been reconfigured by workers’ loss of cross-border mobility, as refugee-workers go into debt throughout the long winter and depend on a continuous flow of credit during slack periods without agricultural work.  As in the case of a mortgage, the shaweesh can, in principle, foreclose and seize a tent if a worker in the camp fails to pay off her debt. However, in practice, workers are under no strict obligation to make monthly or even yearly payments, or to work off their debt within a stipulated period. This means that there are households that have accumulated several years’ worth of debts. In particular, households who lack a sufficient number of able-bodied workers relative to the number of dependents are often so deeply in debt to the shaweesh that they no longer envisage working off their debt or ever returning to Syria, but simply carry on with collecting their meager daily salaries, assured that they will not be evicted as long as they keep working. Thus is the constitutive tension between paternalistic obligation and bonded exploitation that sustains Abu Sharif’s authority. If refugee-workers were to try to find housing within a conventional rental market or to take a bank loan to pay their rent, they would not find the type of flexibility in repayment that the shaweesh offers to camp residents. 

By ensuring the recruitment and reproduction of a highly precarious pool of migrant labor, the shaweesh labor-recruitment system helps ensure that the costs of labor remain low for Lebanese employers in agriculture (which include Lebanese landlords and capitalist farmers who oversee cultivation on behalf of landlords). At the same time, the shaweesh is a facilitator of critical services for workers who are coping with the loss of social benefits provided by the Syrian state and the subsistence they derived from their own land in Syria, both of which were predicated on seasonal migrations that have become increasingly difficult, and in some cases impossible, throughout the war in Syria. As Abu Sharif’s nephew who also works as a shaweesh explained to me, “It feels like everyone is indebted (madyunin). Workers cannot afford anything and the burden is on the shaweesh to keep providing for them.” Thus, despite being an exploiter of labor, the shaweesh is also tied up in complex paternalistic relations with the camp residents, who valorize his function as a provider of essential services, without which they could not survive the high cost of living year-round in Lebanon as refugees. This is captured vividly in the sentiments of Fatima, a worker who has lived in Abu Sharif’s camp since 2006: “Even if the shaweesh exploits me (byistaghilni), I know with him my livelihood is guaranteed (al-ma'ash madmun).” 

While it would be tempting to focus on Abu Sharif as the most visible figure within an obviously exploitative system, it is important to emphasize that his role within Lebanese agriculture is made possible by much broader economic and political forces. It is the drive for a flexible supply of cheap labor among Lebanese employers and landlords that keeps the shaweesh labor-recruitment system alive. The local and regional export agricultural market in Lebanon is highly unregulated. A casual visit to the agricultural market in Qab Elias in western Bekaa Valley, one of the largest suppliers of produce in Lebanon, reveals that prices fluctuate significantly on a day-to-day basis, and sometimes even from hour-to-hour. Lebanese employers are attracted to the flexibility of shaweesh camps, as they can cancel, shorten, or reduce labor assignments depending on the market—or as it is colloquially referred to “on demand” (’al talabiyya)—in contrast to formalized labor recruitment systems in which compensation and benefits are contractually bound and state-mandated.

Lebanese employers pay Abu Sharif eight thousand Lebanese lira (LL) for each worker per shift, from which he takes a two thousand lira commission. This means workers’ take-home wage is six thousand lira per shift.[xv] Called “youmiya” in Arabic, a typical shift lasts five hours. Corresponding roughly to Islamic prayer schedules, the first shift starts after sunrise prayer (salat al-fajr) and the second shift begins from salat al-dhuhur (noon prayer) or salat al-asr (afternoon prayer) until salat al-maghbrib (sunset prayer). In the winter season, workers are lucky if they receive one shift, taking home six thousand lira per person each day. During the summer, each worker can expect to make about twelve thousand lira per day. One of the reasons child labor is so common in Lebanon’s agriculture sector is because families in these circumstances are pooling their limited wages as a single household income: characteristic of what Soviet agrarian economist Alexander Chayanov (1925) famously referred to as the labor-consumer balance. Lebanese employers are afforded flexibility in payments, which are paid to Abu Sharif retroactively rather than as an advance because the number of workers varies so significantly from day-to-day. This means that, for the duration of a given season, Abu Sharif must carefully manage flows of payment from employers in relation to flows of credit to workers, even if he has not yet been paid by employers. Because work assignments are structured around an on-call labor-reserve system, Abu Sharif’s bank account is vulnerable to fluctuations and liquidity problems, especially in the winter low season.

The workers who live in the shaweesh camps, whether male or female, are always referred to collectively by Lebanese employers as “girls” (banat), which indexes their feminized position within the agricultural labor market. For example, a typical way in which a Lebanese employer requests workers for the next day is to say to Abu Sharif, “Bring us fifty girls tomorrow (jibilna khamsin banat bukra).” The designation of certain tasks as “women’s work” and others as “men’s work” is a mechanism of normalizing the cheapening of the wage, as women’s work is consistently undervalued within agricultural labor relations. Lebanese employers expect camp residents to be highly compliant and adaptable to the varying duration, intensity, and nature of their work assignments. I can recall on countless occasions waking up in workers’ tents for the morning shift to the sound of rain, which was always a tell-tale sign that employers would not provide work or wages that day, even if they had made an agreement with Abu Sharif the day before. Further, one of the ways that Lebanese employers increase productivity (and thus, the rate of labor exploitation), is by alternating between a “youmia” schedule (five-hour shifts) and a “maqtu’a” schedule (piece-rate). Instead of a five-hour block of time, a maqtu’a piece-rate measures workers’ output in terms of a set number of filled crates (sharhat) or a stipulated distance, which incentivizes the workers to labor much more quickly. Young, able-bodied workers tend to prefer maqtu’a, because it allows them to finish their shifts early or make more than one shift’s worth of wages within a five-hour period. Older workers and children often struggle to work quickly enough to meet a high piece-rate on a given day. As Chari (2004) argues, piece-rates give the deceptive appearance that workers have greater control over their own labor time. However, in the long run, they undermine workers’ collective bargaining capabilities, which is why they tend to be opposed by unions and organized labor movements.

Alongside the drive for cheap, flexible labor among Lebanese employers, the dynamics of speculation in agricultural land among Lebanese absentee landlords is an additional force sustaining the shaweesh labor recruitment system. Abu Sharif’s camp is situated on a small tract of previously uncultivated agricultural land owned by a Lebanese absentee landlord residing in Qatar. The yearly rent for the camp is 16,667 US dollars (25,000,000 Lebanese lira at the official exchange rate), which Abu Sharif divides among each household and pays to the Lebanese landlord via bank transfer every year. There are thirty tents in the camp, not all of which are filled. The camp residents pay anywhere from 750,000 to 1,000,000 lira per year in rent to Abu Sharif, depending on the size of their tent. 

I recently spoke to Abu Sharif about how the currency crisis in Lebanon has affected the workers living in his camp. “The increase in prices is obscene (ghala’ fahish),” he sighed. “The price of the worker remains the same. And a bag of sugar is 56,000. The worker is beholden to the dollar. God help the worker (Allah ykun bi’awan al-fa’il).” Worse yet, he lamented, the landlord in Qatar—who owns the land on which the camp is situated—insists that the yearly rent be paid in US dollars. This poses a significant problem for Abu Sharif’s accounting, as the workers’ wages are still paid in Lebanese lira. “I told her, 'I have fifteen million lira for you,'” Abu Sharif said, emphasizing that his careful calculations of the camp’s debt and credit balances could not have accounted for such a precipitous devaluation of the Lebanese currency. “I told her, 'Have mercy, Madame, the situation is tragic (al-wada’ ma’sawi). People can barely eat or drink (al-’alam ma ‘am talhaq ta’kul wa-tashrub).” He continued, “I swear to God, everyone in the camp is working on a day’s sustenance alone (al-’alam ‘am yshtaghil ‘ala al-qut al-yawmi). What is the value of a worker’s daily wage of six or seven thousand? Before, it was worth four dollars. That was okay. Today, it is worth one dollar!” 

Though Abu Sharif did not state it explicitly, it appears that his camp faces a real possibility of imminent eviction, as the inflated value of yearly rent payments and the simultaneous devaluation workers’ wages has sent the camp deep into debt. The hundreds of other shaweesh camps across Lebanon’s agricultural fields are surely facing a similar predicament. Within the specific dynamics of Abu Sharif’s camp, the broader contradictions of the Lebanese currency crisis are evident. Contrary to the common-sense notion that such labor arrangements are due to “corruption” or “bad-intentioned opportunists,” the shaweesh labor recruitment system emerged and expanded because it was profitable to a class of prosperous Lebanese landlords and employers. This system now faces the threat of collapse due to the contradictions inherent in the very forces that once made it profitable: Lebanon’s rentier-capitalist approach to food production.

Lebanon’s food crisis has brought into focus a tragic contradiction concerning agriculture: despite its fertile land and capacity for domestic agricultural production, Lebanon imports eighty percent of its foodaccording to some estimatesThe idea of boosting Lebanon’s domestic agricultural production and achieving food sovereignty is now conceived as an urgent necessity at even the highest levels of government. If food sovereignty is to be more than only a slogan, however, we must begin with a perspective from the Syrian laborers who produce the food that nourishes Lebanon’s citizens. Contrary to stereotyped media depictions of Syrians in Lebanon as hapless victims sitting idly in refugee camps, Syrians are a fundamental and valuable pillar of Lebanon’s economy, particularly its food system. While the Lebanese economic crisis and the October revolution have often been framed as national-level issues confined to its citizens, the story of Abu Sharif’s camp suggests that, in the struggle for a more equitable, sustainable food production system, the fate of Syrians and Lebanese is deeply intertwined. 



Acknowledgments: 
An abridged Arabic version of this article can be found on al-Khandak. This article is based on eighteen months of dissertation research generously funded by the National Science Foundation, the Wenner-Gren Foundation, and the Orient-Institut of Beirut. The author thanks Dr. Birgit Schäbler, the OIB fellows and staff, Samer Ghaddar, Stephanie Love, Caity Bolton, Yasemin Ozer, Anna Reumert, Stefan Tarnowski, Aaron Eldridge, Sam Dinger, Amir Reicher, Dorit Price-Levine, Oriol Vallès Codina, Ziad Abu-Rish, and the anonymous reviewers at Jadaliyya for feedback on various versions of this piece. A special thanks to Ali Baba for his assistance with transcriptions and indispensable insights about Eastern Syria.

[i] The term shaweesh is drawn from the Turkish word çavuş, which refers to low-ranking military personnel (Mantran 2012). In Lebanon, it generally refers to someone vested with the responsibility to enforce discipline and is most commonly associated with individuals who oversee camps housing refugee-workers. Similar practices can be found in other regional contexts. Besky (2014) and Chatterjee (2001), for example, refer to the sardar (leader) in India, a contractor who recruits cheap labor to tea plantations, ensures payment, and provides services to workers.


[ii]
 Warsha is a polysemous term that commonly refers to small workshops, such as furniture making or automobile repair shops, or construction sites. In the case of the agricultural camps, it connotes a team of workers who live in a camp, usually overseen by a shaweesh.


[iii]
 Philip McMichael, “A Food Regime Genealogy,” The Journal of Peasant Studies 36, no. 1 (2009): 139–69.


[iv]
 Diana Sarkis Fernández, “‘‘Amnarjaʿ La Wara (We Are Going Backwards)’: Economic Reform and the Politics of Labour in Agrarian Syria,” in The Journal of Peasant Studies (2012): 1–18.


[v]
  Ibid.


[vi]
 Myriam Ababsa, “Syria’s Food Security: From Self-Sufficiency to Hunger as a Weapon,” in Syria: From National Independence to Proxy War, ed. Linda Matar and Ali Kadri (Cham: Springer International Publishing, 2019).


[vii]
 Rami Zurayk, “Civil War and the Devastation of Syria’s Food System,” Journal of Agriculture, Food Systems, and Community Development 3, no. 2 (2013): 7–9.


[viii]
 While Syrian urbanites tend to view “shawaya” as an unequivocally pejorative term, ranging in meaning from “country bumpkin” to “gypsy” and generally referring to tribal populations from northeastern Syria, it has a more complex connotation among rural Eastern Syrians themselves. According to Lancaster and Lancaster (2012), the term shawaya refers to pastoralists who herd sheep as their main source of livelihood, usually of a lower status than camel herders. Under the French Mandate, colonial officials categorized shawaya as “semi-sedentary tribes” in contrast to the “real Bedouin,” sometimes depicting them as “‘degenerate Bedouin’ who had lost their noble virtues” (Lange 2005) who were “associated with lying, theft, and more licentious sexual mores” (Lange 2015). In contrast, in my own research, the word shawaya carries a more positive connotation and is a common self-designation. For example, refugee-workers in the camp proudly refer to their dialect of Arabic as shawiya. Workers explain the word’s origin as a reference to the verb shawy (to grill), which they see as a mark of their reputation for generosity as “those who grill meat” (Lange 2005).


[ix]
 Farshad Araghi, “The Invisible Hand and the Visible Foot: Peasants, Dispossession and Globalisation,” in Peasants and Globalization: Political Economy, Rural Transformation and the Agrarian Question, ed. A.H. Akram-Lodhi and Cristobal Kay (London: Routledge, 2007).


[x]
 Salim Nasr, “Backdrop to Civil War: The Crisis of Lebanese Capitalism,” MERIP Reports 73 (1978): 3–13.


[xi]
  Ibid.


[xii]
  Ibid.


[xiii]
  Nathalie Allam, “Farming Is like Gambling: An Examination of the Decline of Produce Farming in Lebanon’s Central Bekaa Valley” (M.A. Thesis, The George Washington University, 2011).


[xiv]
 Ben White, “Generational Dynamics in Agriculture: Reflections on Rural Youth and Farming Futures,” Cahiers Agricultures 24, no. 6 (2015): 330–34.


[xv]
 The Lebanese lira has been pegged to the US dollar since the 1990s as part of Lebanon’s post-civil war neoliberal transition. For the past several years, signs of a looming economic crisis were increasingly apparent, including capital flight, skyrocketing public debt, and a protracted trade deficit. In October 2019, popular uprisings spread across the country as Lebanon’s economy spiralled into further crisis. Compounded by the effects of COVID-19, the Lebanese lira has been severely devalued. Until October 2019, a worker’s wage rate of six thousand lira per five-hour shift was worth four dollars. Today, it is worth less than one dollar.

Works Cited


Myriam Ababsa, “Syria’s Food Security: From Self-Sufficiency to Hunger as a Weapon,” in Syria: From National Independence to Proxy War, ed. Linda Matar and Ali Kadri (Cham: Springer International Publishing, 2019). 

Nathalie Allam, “Farming Is like Gambling: An Examination of the Decline of Produce Farming in Lebanon’s Central Bekaa Valley” (M.A. Thesis, The George Washington University, 2011).

Farshad Araghi, “The Invisible Hand and the Visible Foot: Peasants, Dispossession and Globalisation,” in Peasants and Globalization: Political Economy, Rural Transformation and the Agrarian Question, ed. A.H. Akram-Lodhi and Cristobal Kay (London: Routledge, 2007).

Sarah Besky, The Darjeeling Distinction: Labor and Justice on Fair-Trade Tea Plantations in India (Berkeley: University of California Press, 2013).

Sharad Chari, Fraternal Capital: Peasant-Workers, Self-Made Men, and Globalization in Provincial India (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 2004).

Piya Chatterjee, A Time for Tea: Women, Labor, and Post/Colonial Politics on an Indian Plantation (Durham: Duke University Press, 2001). 

Alexander V. Chayanoc, The Theory of Peasant Economy, ed. Daniel Thorner, Basile Kerblay, and R.E.F. Smith (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1966 [1925]).

Fidelity Lancaster and William Lancaster, “Shawiya- Syrian and the Arabian Peninsula,” Encyclopedia of Islam, 2nd. edition (Leiden: Brill, 2012). 

Katharina Lange, “Shawaya: Economic Mélange, Pure Origins? Outsiders’ and Insiders’ Accounts of Tribal Identity in Northern Syria,” in Shifts and Drifts in Nomad-Sedentary Relations, ed. Wiesbaden, Reichert, Stefan Leder and Bernhard Streck (Dr. Ludwig Reichert Verlag, 2005). 

Katharina Lange, “‘Bedouin’ and ‘Shawaya’: The Performative Constitution of Tribal Identities in Syria during the French Mandate and Today,” Journal of the Economic and Social History of the Orient 58, no. 1–2(2015): 200–35.

Robert Mantran, “Ca’ush,” in Encyclopaedia of Islam, 2nd edition (Leiden: Brill, 2012). 

Philip McMichael, “A Food Regime Genealogy,” The Journal of Peasant Studies 36, no. 1 (2009): 139–69.

Salim Nasr, “Backdrop to Civil War: The Crisis of Lebanese Capitalism,” MERIP Reports 73 (1978): 3–13.

Diana Sarkis Fernández, “‘‘Amnarjaʿ La Wara (We Are Going Backwards)’: Economic Reform and the Politics of Labour in Agrarian Syria,” in The Journal of Peasant Studies (2012): 1–18.

Ben White, “Generational Dynamics in Agriculture: Reflections on Rural Youth and Farming Futures,” Cahiers Agricultures 24, no. 6 (2015): 330–34. 

Rami Zurayk, “Civil War and the Devastation of Syria’s Food System,” Journal of Agriculture, Food Systems, and Community Development 3, no. 2 (2013): 7–9.